From twod@umich.edu Sun Oct 27 10:27:12 2002 Date: Sat, 26 Oct 2002 14:47:52 -0400 From: twod To: twod@umich.edu Subject: New Scientist | Evolution of the Car ORIGINAL URL: http://www.newscientist.com/hottopics/cars/article.jsp?id=22944900&sub=Socio-economic%20issues TITLE: Whose roads are they anyway? ABSTRACT: Every day, millions of cars choke us to death in city centres the world over. Ironically, while many people neither own nor drive one, the car has proved so seductive that it has turned into one of the most environmentally destructive forces of our time. One man who thinks we can't carry on like this is Phil Goodwin of University College London, a leading expert on traffic congestion. He wants Britain to be the envy of the Western worldby charging motorists to drive in city centres. And London should soon become the largest Western city to experiment with the idea. Not, as Goodwin explains to Mick Hamer, that he expects an easy ride . . . (09/06/2001)     By Mick Hamer Many people think the simple way to solve the congestion is to build more roads. What do you think? In Britain the government is planning to increase spending on building new roads and widening others. This will cost 60 billion. But the government's own forecasts show that the effect on the inter-urban road network will be to reduce journey times by a second per mile by only the end of the decade. Averaged over the whole road network, the saving is a quarter of a second per mile each year. The normal variation in travel times is around 20 per cent, so your journey time could already vary by 15 seconds per mile from day to day, let alone year to year. Real people can't easily distinguish fractions of a second. If road building won't solve congestion, what will? The defining relationship in transport is the speed-flow curve. This shows that the more traffic there is on a road, the slower it goes. There are three ways out of that. One way is to build more roads to try to keep up with increasing traffic. That has been tried for half a century or more. A second way is to organise the road system more efficiently. There's always scope for squeezing a bit more out of the existing network by optimising traffic signals and one-way systems and so on. The problem is you end up with a system that is very close to capacity, and that is a recipe for chaos. The closer the network is to capacity, the bigger the jams when something random goes wrong, such as a burst water main. So what's the third way? Would it involve charging motorists? You need to build in some redundancy, by controlling the volume of traffic. That's been the dominant intellectual advance for the past decade. The idea that you could solve congestion only by charging motorists or only by improving public transport so people would voluntarily leave their cars at home is mistaken. It's the word "only" that undermines it all. It's like building a dam halfway across a river. So you need both carrots and sticks? The carrots are vote-winners but don't work on their own. And the sticks, if you're serious enough, do work but they don't give you a long enough political life to see them through. They've tried pay-as-you-drive in Singapore and Oslo successfully. How will you persuade Britons to leave their cars at home? The traditional wisdom on road pricing was that you could prove that if prices reflected the true costs of travelincluding the cost of congestion and pollutionthen the system would be more efficient and everyone would benefit whatever the government spent the revenue on. This was a political disaster because what it did was create a medium-sized group of people, including many motorists, who are utterly hostile to the idea because they lose from it, and a very large group of peoplethe majoritywho benefit from the revenue the government has to spend, but indirectly and invisibly. So I argued that the revenue should be spent on improving the alternatives to motoring so it increases the support for road pricing. If road pricing is taken up outside London, would it be introduced by central government or by local councils? Local councils. Unless it's done this way it simply won't happen. The idea of road pricing has been around before. You launch into it with great enthusiasm and the closer you get to it the more the opposition builds up and you just kick it into another Royal Commission or study. It's happened over and over again. I argued that local authorities should be allowed to introduce itgiving them the incentive that they could keep the money and spend it on public transport. Most local authorities would be scared and only a few would go ahead. These cities would show how well it works and this would build up public support. It's been much the same with pedestrianisation, which I count as one of the great success stories of the past 25 years. Every city worried whether banning cars would destroy its city centre and create chaos, but now we all know it works. I think it will be the same with road pricing. What effect do you see it having in London? At the moment the discussions are about a rather narrowly defined area and a non-scary price level and, of course, the smaller the area and the smaller the price, the less impact it has. But I think it's a question of what process does it start? Which direction does it take you in? You could imagine the thing actually working quite nicely with the increased pricing reducing traffic levels in certain important areas and then a radical expansion of bus priority networks. I think we've gone about as far as we can go with the disconnected bits of bus lanes. The thing is to put it all together and create a network that has to go, obviously, over a much greater area than simply central London. Together with the rail investment programmes, you could get a complete transformation. What would you do about the other part of your strategy, improving public transport? Commuters have a lot to put up with. Yes, and unreliability is probably the main criticism. It may well be preferable to have a lower average speed that you can rely on. I don't think we've had a level playing field for about half a century. The system has favoured car use, which has meant that traffic has grown more than it should have done. It's time to shift the balance in favour of public transport, cycling and walking, and a more coherent strategy for managing the volume of road traffic. This could deliver a considerably better outcome than the government's spending plan. What started you off on this line of thinking? There was a classic piece of research back in 1964 that attracted me because the message was counterintuitive: if everyone travelled by the slowest form of transport (bus), they get to their destination faster than if they all travelled by the fastest method (car). Because buses carry more people than cars, if you persuade motorists to travel by bus you cut the number of vehicles on the road and speed up the traffic. It was the first time I'd seen such a fascinating argument. Unexpected results are always interesting. So is the way we model transport all wrong? Yes. One of the key assumptions in older transport models, for example, was that the total volume of traffic is fixed. If you built a new road the only thing that could change was the route that drivers chose. This was initially only a simplifying assumption, a way of getting the mathematics to work, but it became established thinking and was used for assessing road schemeswith seriously distorted results. You mean that the forecasts actually assumed that new roads wouldn't generate traffic? Yes. And they also meant that if you closed a road, or pedestrianised an area, or put a bus lane in, then there would be no reduction in traffic. We know now that both are wrong empirically. I contributed to two studies on this. If you build more roads you get some extra traffic. The reverse is also true: if you reduce road capacity you get less traffic. They're obviously two sides of the same coin, but it's not yet clear whether they're exact mirror images. The speed of or size of response may be rather different. Are there other false assumptions in these transport models? All the widely used models assume that when you observe traffic levels at a point in time the whole system has reached stable equilibrium. And when you forecast traffic levels for 2010 or 2020, they will have reached a new equilibrium. I don't think this is tenable. Research shows it can take up to 10 years for people to respond fully to changes in petrol prices, fare hikes or new services. In some senses you could say it's never complete but, for practical purposes, the response to a major change is greatest in the first 3 to 5 years and broadly complete after 10 years. Once you look at travel choice as a dynamic process, it emerges that the sensitivity of the market to price changes is probably twice, maybe more than twice as great as once thought. Can you give an example? Take buses. For as long as I can remember the industry has assumed that a 10 per cent increase in bus fares means you lose around 3 per cent of your passengers shortly after the increase. So putting up the fares is worth it because you can pocket a 7 per cent increase in revenue. But in the long term, fares increases can lose you 8 or 9 per cent of the passengersand in some segments of your markets you will lose more than you gain. But these losses may be happening years later so you blame it on something else, such as the state of the economy. And the public transport industry, for most of our lifetimes, has eroded its own market, year by year. That has to be reversed. Do we need new and different models for the 21st century? Yes. The current methods don't help you understand how to change people's behaviour, or how long it takes for effects to build up, or in which order policies need to be implementedoften the three most important practical questions. Most scientific modellers are now used to asymmetric relationships, chaos and non-linear systems. Economic models take lags into account as a matter of course. So in the first years of the 21st century it would be nice to bring transport methodology into the last quarter of the 20th century. [shim.gif] From New Scientist Magazine   09 June 01